• C++ Programming for Financial Engineering
    Highly recommended by thousands of MFE students. Covers essential C++ topics with applications to financial engineering. Learn more Join!
    Python for Finance with Intro to Data Science
    Gain practical understanding of Python to read, understand, and write professional Python code for your first day on the job. Learn more Join!
    An Intuition-Based Options Primer for FE
    Ideal for entry level positions interviews and graduate studies, specializing in options trading arbitrage and options valuation models. Learn more Join!

Derivatives and Mass Financial Destruction

Joined
6/5/07
Messages
348
Points
26
Derivatives and Mass Financial Destruction

Complex financial products can be useful if regulated


Proposals for a makeover of the financial system include reform of the credit derivatives market, which offers over $50 trillion of default insurance coverage. Do investors need that much insurance, or is this mainly a dangerous casino operating under the radar of regulators -- until a major financial institution like AIG needs a bailout? What sort of reform is needed?

The seller of protection in a credit derivatives contract receives premiums from the buyer of protection until maturity, or until default of the named borrower. Contracts are negotiated over the counter, not on an exchange, so it is difficult to know how much insurance exists on each borrower, or to know who has insured whom, and for how much.

That privacy is not unusual in the normal course of business contracts. What is unusual is the size of the potential claims. There is a public interest in knowing that systemically important sellers of protection have not overdone it. If a large bank or insurance company does not have enough capital to cover settlement claims, then its failure, or the threat of it, can cause mayhem, as we have just seen.

The largest credit derivatives positions are held by big-bank credit derivatives dealers. Because they intermediate between buyers and sellers, dealers often have nearly offsetting positions. For example, according to J.P. Morgan's latest quarterly report, it had bought protection coverage on $5.2 trillion of debt principal, and sold protection on $5 trillion. The vast quantity of outstanding derivatives in the global market is therefore not a good gauge of the effective amount of insurance offered.

Of the $532 trillion notional amount of financial instruments covered by over-the-counter derivatives in June of this year -- including credit derivatives, interest-rate swaps and equity derivatives -- the International Swaps and Derivatives Association estimates potential exposures to counterparties of $2.7 trillion. These exposures are further reduced by collateral held against the potential failure of counterparties.

Of roughly $350 billion in credit derivative settlement claims that arose in Lehman's default, about $6 billion in actual settlement payments were scheduled for payment yesterday, after canceling offsetting claims. For illustration, suppose that Goldman Sachs had sold protection to the point that it owed $7 billion in Lehman settlement claims, and had purchased protection on which it was owed $7.5 billion. In this situation, Goldman would collect a net of $0.5 billion, unless a counterparty fails to pay. Suppose that one of Goldman's counterparties, say a hedge fund, had failed to pay Goldman a $100 million settlement claim. If Goldman had received the industry-average 65% collateralization from its counterparty, it would keep the collateral and be out $35 million. Goldman could then pursue additional recoveries as a claimant in the hedge fund's bankruptcy. The Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation, which keeps records of the majority of credit derivatives trades and settlements, reported yesterday that there were no payment failures on scheduled Lehman credit derivative settlements.

So far, the credit derivatives settlement process has worked smoothly through several large defaults, but the safety of the settlement process could be improved significantly. Because dealers lay off such large positions with each other, a large fraction of their exposures is unnecessary. For example, suppose that Bank A is exposed to Bank B for $1 billion, while B is exposed to C for $1 billion, and C is exposed to A for $1 billion, all on the same underlying named borrower. That circle of exposures is eliminated if all three banks clear their positions with the same central clearing counterparty. Because Bank A is long and short by the same amount, it would have no settlement payment to make or to receive from the clearing counterparty. Banks B and C would likewise have no potential loss. In practice, exposures would not be offset so neatly, but a large fraction of them would.

The Fed is pressing dealers to quickly establish clearing in credit derivatives. The dealers have expressed an interest in using their own clearing counterparty, the Chicago Clearing Corporation. Alternatively, they could clear credit derivatives with a new joint venture of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange and Citadel (a large hedge fund). Either way, regulators should ensure that a clearing counterparty is extremely well capitalized and has strong operational controls.

Unfortunately, the urgency to set up clearing for credit derivatives may lead us to miss the opportunity to reduce exposures even further by clearing credit derivatives along with other forms of over-the-counter derivatives, such as interest-rate swaps and equity derivatives, which represent similarly large amounts of risk transfer. Regulators should press dealers to clear more types of derivatives with the same clearing house.

That investors can benefit from a market for insurance against default risk does not seem controversial. The market premiums offered on credit derivatives also provide investors with "price discovery" of the financial health of corporations and sovereign states. (Although trading is private, samples of prices are disseminated by financial news services.)

There is a public interest in limiting the exposure of large, systemically important financial institutions, relative to their capital, whether from derivatives or from other forms of risk taking. We were supposed to have had such limits, but they were not effective, and will presumably be revisited by regulators soon.

Regulators should also have access to more detailed information on the potential exposures of large financial players to each other. But general public disclosure of specific derivatives trades seems unnecessary in most cases, can lower incentives to invest efficiently, and runs counter to our norms for privacy. We do nothing like this in other financial markets, such as those for common stocks, except when positions are large enough to suggest the potential control of public corporations. (Derivatives do not carry control rights.)

Public disclosure can nevertheless be a good disinfectant whenever sufficiently severe conflicts of interest lead to inefficient control of risk (moral hazard) or to unfair exploitation of counterparties. If a lender can largely insure itself against its borrower's default, it has lessened its interest in the financial health of the borrower, and may neglect to monitor the borrower. Default losses to the lender would be passed on to credit derivatives counterparties, who may not be aware of the conflict of interest.

When unconstrained by good regulations, derivatives can be financial weapons of mass destruction. Our new regulations should be smart and surgical.

source: Derivatives and Mass Financial Destruction - WSJ.com

***
Found this to have some useful information w/r/t magnitude of actual net exposure.
 
Nice article.
I think regulators are baffled with the size of the CDS market and they cannot even decide where to start. If we look at the past, imposing an exchange/clearing house will not be beneficial.
However, they can start a new clearing house and try to attract a few big players as dealers. This enticement should not be difficult since SEC and especialy Fed have an upper hand on a few investment banks that depend on their direct support.

After that, slowly te new exchange can gather new contracts and slowly work to move offsetting existing contracts to this new place. Current fear of counter-party default might balance the banks interest to clear all transactions.

Within 5-7 years, these new regulated markets will increase number of players, allow small investors (same process as stock market), maybe more work for much hated quants ...
 
Nice article.
I think regulators are baffled with the size of the CDS market and they cannot even decide where to start. If we look at the past, imposing an exchange/clearing house will not be beneficial.
However, they can start a new clearing house and try to attract a few big players as dealers. This enticement should not be difficult since SEC and especialy Fed have an upper hand on a few investment banks that depend on their direct support.

After that, slowly te new exchange can gather new contracts and slowly work to move offsetting existing contracts to this new place. Current fear of counter-party default might balance the banks interest to clear all transactions.

Within 5-7 years, these new regulated markets will increase number of players, allow small investors (same process as stock market), maybe more work for much hated quants ...

I think your reasoning is sound, but I'm not sure what precedent the past provides for "imposing an exchange/clearing house." Can you explain?

The imperative from the regulatory side is the issue of statutory capital requirements.

I posted the following to my blog last night, after the conference on hedging illiquid instruments (where the discussion turned to CDS netting and actual liability), and before this article was published:


Anna Schwartz, in an interview published in the WSJ October 18, got me thinking...

What say we take what's left of that $700 bn and dream up some kind of incentive to get an exchange set up to transparently price the structured OTC inventory (or at least its major parts) ASAP?

All assets that impact statutory capital have to be priced without any further delay (wasn't that the spirit of FASB 157?).

Then let the market do its thing. It's going to anyway, eventually. The sooner, the better.

Instead of bailing out the banks which were rather poor stewards of the money they had, why not invest in the market infrastructure? Some of the bright lights at the NYME?, for example, are making some headway. If a deal can be struck, then take a position in the solution instead of the cause of the problem.

If the government has to be involved, let it be in a way that upholds markets, not supercedes them.

You'll probably still have to bail out the banks, but at least the problem will be on its way to being solved. And getting an exchange working properly will very likely speed the process and reduce its cost to taxpayers. Oh, and it will create value and wealth in the process.

The market will fix the problem if it has the tools.

Wouldn't it be cool if America leveraged this situation into a leadership position in these new markets, like it had once in equities, options and futures?

no, I'm not plugging the blog. It's just proper to cite myself this way.
 
Good blog entry, fully agree

I think your reasoning is sound, but I'm not sure what precedent the past provides for "imposing an exchange/clearing house." Can you explain?

In U.S. there are a set of different exchanges, however this is not true in all countries (e.g. China, Brasil, Russia etc).
For instance, in Romania, the clearing house was started by an institution reporting to Parliament. Then it slowly moved towards a more private statute, still far from that.
This worked fine since there is no competing domestic exchanges.

It does not apply in U.S. derivative market where dealers have their own ad-hoc "exchanges" with an overall large volume. I was supporting the idea of slowly pushing into this market instead of enacting a law to ban these OTC markets ...
 
Good blog entry, fully agree



In U.S. there are a set of different exchanges, however this is not true in all countries (e.g. China, Brasil, Russia etc).
For instance, in Romania, the clearing house was started by an institution reporting to Parliament. Then it slowly moved towards a more private statute, still far from that.
This worked fine since there is no competing domestic exchanges.

It does not apply in U.S. derivative market where dealers have their own ad-hoc "exchanges" with an overall large volume. I was supporting the idea of slowly pushing into this market instead of enacting a law to ban these OTC markets ...

Ah. My perspective is the US approach, as this is what is in question.

The problem with the OTC market in the case of something that is so large and is linked to statutory capital was expressed well in the piece, I thought:

That privacy is not unusual in the normal course of business contracts. What is unusual is the size of the potential claims. There is a public interest in knowing that systemically important sellers of protection have not overdone it. If a large bank or insurance company does not have enough capital to cover settlement claims, then its failure, or the threat of it, can cause mayhem, as we have just seen.

Separately, markets at large require transparency (along with anonymity, as appropriate). Standardization makes that doable.

If the 900 foot tail wasn't wagging the dog, and if taxpayers weren't directly on the hook to the major players, I would be more sanguine about the lassaiz faire approach.

But it is, and we are, and price discovery is long past being imperative. This is a perfect opportunity to show the appropriate role of limited (the author says, "smart and surgical") regulation in markets. If only they get it.
 
Back
Top