• C++ Programming for Financial Engineering
    Highly recommended by thousands of MFE students. Covers essential C++ topics with applications to financial engineering. Learn more Join!
    Python for Finance with Intro to Data Science
    Gain practical understanding of Python to read, understand, and write professional Python code for your first day on the job. Learn more Join!
    An Intuition-Based Options Primer for FE
    Ideal for entry level positions interviews and graduate studies, specializing in options trading arbitrage and options valuation models. Learn more Join!

Seduced by a Model

Joined
5/2/06
Messages
11,750
Points
273
By SIMON JOHNSON AND JAMES KWAK
Simon Johnson, a professor of entrepreneurship at M.I.T.s Sloan School of Management, is the former chief economist at the International Monetary Fund. James Kwak, a former McKinsey consultant, is currently a student at Yale Law School.

Economic and financial models have come in for a lot of criticism in the context of the global financial crisis, much of it deserved. One of the primary targets is models that financial institutions widely used to (mis)estimate risk, like value at risk (VAR) models for measuring risk exposures (which weve discussed elsewhere) or the Gaussian copula function for quantifying the risk of a pool of assets.

In September, the Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations of the House Science and Technology Committee held a hearing on the role of risk models in the financial crisis and how they should be used by financial regulators, if at all. The hearing focused largely on VAR models, which seek to quantify the amount that a trader (or an entire bank) stands to lose on a given day, with a certain confidence level. (For example, a one-day 1 percent VAR of $10 million means that on 99 percent of days you will lose less than $10 million.)

Although the witnesses ranged from Nassim Taleb, who has been arguing for years that VAR models are toxic, to Gregg Berman, who heads a company that develops VAR models for customers, there was surprising agreement on the problems of VAR.

As Richard Bookstaber put it, VAR depends on three assumptions, all of which are generally false: not all assets, particularly illiquid ones, are included in the VAR calculation; estimates are based on past data that is unrepresentative of the future; and because financial returns exhibit fat tails (extreme outcomes are more likely than you would expect), VAR estimates tell you very little about how bad things can get that last 1 percent of the time.

The question, then, is what to do about it.

One thing that seems clear is that risk models that are designed to function in normal market conditions should not be relied upon to predict outcomes in times of crisis. On this account, VAR doesnt kill banks; rather, executives who dont recognize the limits of VAR kill banks. As Mr. Bookstaber put it,

one has to look beyond VAR, to culprits such as sheer stupidity or collective management failure: The risk managers missed the growing inventory [of risky assets], or did not have the courage of their conviction to insist on its reduction, or the senior management was not willing to heed their demands. Whichever the reason, VAR was not central to this crisis.

Given that everyone is agreeing sophisticated risk models are worthless in crises, it seems particularly remarkable that regulators allowed some banks to use their in-house models in determine their own capital requirements since one of the purposes of capital requirements is precisely to provide a cushion that protects banks (and their creditors, and taxpayers) in the event of a crisis.

The obvious solution is that regulators should rely on cruder constraints, such as an absolute limit on leverage that banks cannot arbitrage around (one of the recommendations of Treasurys recent white paper on capital requirements, which we discussed here), or periodic stress tests that estimate how bank asset portfolios will perform in a real crisis.

But there is a more interesting question to ask as well: Why did VAR become so popular? Its important to remember that competition among models is shaped by the human beings who create and use them, and those human beings have their own incentives.

David Colander made this point about economic models: The sociology of the economics profession gave preference to elegant mathematical models that could describe the world using the smallest number of parameters. Common sense does not advance one very far within the economics profession, he says.

A similar point can be made about VAR models. Sure, maybe all the financial professionals who design and work with VAR know about its shortcomings, both mathematical and practical. But nevertheless, using VAR brought concrete benefits to specific actors in the banking world by helping them rationalize bad bets. If common sense would lead a risk manager to crack down on a trader taking large, risky bets, then the trader is better off if the risk manager uses VAR instead.

Not only that, but imagine the situation of the chief risk manager of a bank in, say, 2004. As Andrew Lo has argued, if he tried to reduce his banks exposure to structured securities such as collateralized debt obligations, he would be out of a job; VAR gave him a handy tool to rationalize a situation that defied common sense but that made his bosses only too happy. And at the top levels, chief executives and directors who probably did not understand the shortcomings of VAR were biased in its favor because it told them a story they wanted to hear.

In other words, models succeed because they meet the needs of real human beings, and VAR was just what they needed during the boom. And we should assume that a profit-seeking financial sector will continue to invent models that further the objectives of the individuals and institutions that use them. The implication is that regulators need to resist the group think of large financial institutions. If everyone involved is using the same road map of risks, we will all drive off the cliff again together.

Seduced by a Model - Economix Blog - NYTimes.com
 
Back
Top